CL3.2.3
Economics and Econometrics of Climate Change: evaluating the drivers, impacts, and policies of climate change

CL3.2.3

EDI
Economics and Econometrics of Climate Change: evaluating the drivers, impacts, and policies of climate change
Convener: Luke Jackson | Co-conveners: Felix Pretis, Susana Campos-MartinsECSECS, Sam Heft-Neal, David Stainforth
Presentations
| Thu, 26 May, 15:10–16:40 (CEST)
 
Room 1.34

Presentations: Thu, 26 May | Room 1.34

Chairpersons: David Stainforth, Moritz Schwarz
Emission and Climate
15:10–15:16
|
EGU22-6392
|
ECS
|
On-site presentation
|
Sebastian Jensen, Eric Hillebrand, and Mikkel Bennedsen

We project carbon dioxide emissions through 2100 using a reduced-form model and national-level scenarios for per capita gross domestic product from the Shared Socioeconomic Pathways (SSPs). We propose a novel neural network-based panel data model that combines country fixed effects with a long short-term memory (LSTM) recurrent neural network regression component that takes into account time implicitly by building memory and letting model predictions depend on the income path of a country. For scenarios with low socioeconomic challenges for mitigation SSP1 and SSP4, our emissions projections appear consistent with baseline projections from structural integrated assessment models (IAMs) that are meant to describe future developments in absence of new climate policies. For scenarios with medium and high socioeconomic challenges for mitigation SSP2, SSP3, and SSP5, our emissions projections appear the most consistent with mitigation projections from IAMs that target a forcing level of 6.0 W/m2 by 2100.

How to cite: Jensen, S., Hillebrand, E., and Bennedsen, M.: Apocalypse Now? Projecting CO2 Emissions with Neural Networks, EGU General Assembly 2022, Vienna, Austria, 23–27 May 2022, EGU22-6392, https://doi.org/10.5194/egusphere-egu22-6392, 2022.

15:16–15:22
|
EGU22-2356
|
On-site presentation
Erica Thompson, Joel Katzav, James Risbey, David Stainforth, Seamus Bradley, and Matthias Frisch

Probability distribution functions (PDFs) are widely used in projections of future climate, projections of the impacts of future climate, and by climate services aiming to provide information to support practical climate change adaptation. Furthermore they are often used as a means of connecting these different activities and linking the variety of disciplines involved in climate science and climate social science.

Here we present an assessment of when such probability distributions misrepresent our uncertainty and a discussion of how we might recognise when such misrepresentations occur [1]. We go on to provide a collection of alternatives to probability distributions for use in such situations.

We start by categorising the ways that probability distributions can misrepresent the state of our knowledge about future climate. Such misrepresentation is of importance because it may adversely affect practical societal decisions, particularly in regard to adaptation activities, as well as misdirecting other research efforts.

We follow this with a discussion of how we might identify such misrepresentations. Doing so would help us communicate climate information better and consequently provided better reasoned and more robust scientific conclusions and societal decisions. Such assessments are an important component in the evaluation of climate information provided by climate services: what aspects of the information can be described as actionable.

We consider two perspectives on these issues. On one, available theory and evidence in climate science essentially excludes using probability distributions to represent our uncertainty. On the other, which represents a significant strand of current practice, probability distributions can legitimately be provided by relying on appropriate expert judgement and the recognition of associated risks.  We discuss the reasoning behind each perspective, framed in terms of the analysis of climate models and expert judgement.

Finally we explore alternatives to the use of probability distributions. We describe two formal alternatives, namely imprecise probabilities and possibilistic distribution functions, as well as some informal possibilistic alternatives. We suggest that the possibilistic alternatives are preferable.

 

[1] Katzav, Thompson, Risbey, Stainforth, Bradley and Frisch, On the appropriate and inappropriate uses of probability distributions in climate projections and some alternatives, Climatic Change, 2021.

How to cite: Thompson, E., Katzav, J., Risbey, J., Stainforth, D., Bradley, S., and Frisch, M.: On the use, misuse and alternatives to probability distributions in descriptions of future climate, EGU General Assembly 2022, Vienna, Austria, 23–27 May 2022, EGU22-2356, https://doi.org/10.5194/egusphere-egu22-2356, 2022.

15:22–15:28
|
EGU22-1240
|
Presentation form not yet defined
Global, hemispheric, and regional temperature anomalies - how different are they and what does it mean?
(withdrawn)
Marc Gronwald
15:28–15:34
|
EGU22-2607
|
Presentation form not yet defined
|
Doris Folini, Felix Kübler, Aleksandra Malova, and Simon Scheidegger

We develop a generic and transparent calibration strategy for simple climate models used in economics. The goal is to choose the free model parameters such as to best match the output of large-scale Earth System Models from the Coupled Model Intercomparison Project, run on pre-defined emissions scenarios. We propose to jointly use four different test cases that are considered pivotal in the climate science literature: two highly idealized tests to separately examine the carbon cycle and the temperature response, and two tests closer to real scenarios, incorporating gradual changes in CO2 emissions and exogenous forcings.

To illustrate the applicability of our method, we re-calibrate the free parameters of the climate part of the seminal DICE-2016 model for three different CMIP5 model responses: the multi-model mean as well as two CMIP5 models that exhibit extreme but still permissible equilibrium climate sensitivities. As an additional novelty, our calibrations of DICE-2016 allow for an arbitrary time step in the model explicitly. By applying our comprehensive suite of tests, we i) confirm that both the temperature equations and the carbon cycle in DICE-2016 are miscalibrated and ii) we show that by re-calibrating coefficients all CMIP5 targets considered can be well matched.

Finally, we apply the economic model from DICE-2016 in combination with the newly calibrated climate model to compute the social cost of carbon and optimal warming. We find the social cost of carbon to be similar to DICE-2016, while the optimal long-run temperature is almost one degree lower.  The social cost of carbon turns out to be much less sensitive to the discount rate than in DICE-2016. We explain how the model's climate part relates to these differences. As the temperature in DICE-2016 under optimal mitigation falls outside the range of CMIP5 projections, we caution that one might want to be skeptical about policy advice based on DICE-2016.

How to cite: Folini, D., Kübler, F., Malova, A., and Scheidegger, S.: The climate in climate economics, EGU General Assembly 2022, Vienna, Austria, 23–27 May 2022, EGU22-2607, https://doi.org/10.5194/egusphere-egu22-2607, 2022.

15:34–15:40
|
EGU22-12067
|
ECS
|
On-site presentation
|
Claudia Wieners

The stylised Integrated Assessment Model DICE by Nobel laureate William Nordhaus has been criticised for its overly simplifying assumptions, yet is still widely used as a testbed model (e.g. for investigating policy effects of climate tipping [Cai, Lenton and Lontzek, 2015] or solar geoengineering [Helwegen et al., 2019]) and, occasionally, policy advice. Surprisingly, much of the past criticism was focusing on the extremely difficult issue of modelling climate-induced damage, while the equally problematic formulation of mitigation costs [Grubb, Wieners and Yang, 2021] remained relatively unchallenged, despite being a more tractable problem. In particular, DICE’s mitigation costs at any time t only depend on the fraction of emissions avoided at time t, ignoring the fact that past mitigation investment affects future costs (“if you build a wind park this year, it will still save carbon next year”).

In the current study, I introduce EnergICE, a DICE version with a still simple, but dynamically more consistent energy sector. Rather than picking a fraction of emissions (w.r.t. a baseline) to be avoided by unspecified means, the social planner now makes investment decisions: To fulfil the system’s energy demand, the planner can choose from “brown” (fuel-using) and “green” (renewable) power plants. As green energy cannot always be generated (dark, windless days), storage facilities can also be built. Green plants have initially only slightly higher lifetime costs than brown ones, but storage is very expensive. Learning-by-doing effects reduce the price of both green plants and storages, while brown plants are a mature technology with little learning potential. On the other hand, fuel becomes more expensive with cumulative use, as harder-to-extract reservoirs must be mined once the easy-to-extract ones are exhausted. Therefore even without climate change, some green transition will eventually occur. However, the transition can remain incomplete for decades, with only enough green plants for the “sunny” periods, but fuel-based energy being used in “dark” times.

A simplified version of EnergICE without storage also exists; in that version, the green plants implicitly contain a storage facility and are thus initially expensive. While capturing the investment-like character of mitigation, the simplified version is hardly more complex than the original DICE model; in particular, it does not add a decision variable.

As a test case, the EnergICE model is used to study the desirability (or undesireability) of solar geoengineering under uncertain climate sensitivity. The choice of the energy model (DICE vs EnergICE) can alter the “optimal” level of solar geoengineering by up to a factor of 6, which illustrates that the treatment of mitigation deserves more attention when using DICE-like models as testbed for new concepts.

How to cite: Wieners, C.: EnergICE: a Simple but more Realistic Energy Sector for the DICE model (with an application to solar geoengineering), EGU General Assembly 2022, Vienna, Austria, 23–27 May 2022, EGU22-12067, https://doi.org/10.5194/egusphere-egu22-12067, 2022.

Climate Impacts
15:40–15:46
|
EGU22-11078
|
Virtual presentation
|
Thomas Leirvik, Menghan Yuan, and Hande Karabiyik

Global warming has slowed economic growth and aggravated global economic inequality, affecting individual wellbeing in a wide-ranging aspects. Quantifying these historical impacts is critical for informing climate change mitigation and adaptation and achieving a more equitable economic development. This paper extends existing literature by exploring the effects of precipitation on economic growth. Based on a panel of 169 countries over the period 1961-2019, we demonstrate a statistically significant non-linear effect of precipitation on economic growth, such that output is maximized at around 2.03 metres of annual total precipitation. Despite of the significant sensitivity of precipitation, we find its impacts are relatively small and are completely overwhelmed by the effects of temperature. We examine the historical marginal effects of climate change and find realized temperature has lowered the annual global growth rate by 0.31 percentage points per year on average, whereas realized precipitation has increased the annual economic growth by roughly 0.01 percentage points. Furthermore, we highlight that countries endowed with different climate conditions exhibit substantially different reactions to historical climate change. For example, Europe and Central Asia countries have benefited both from temperature rising and precipitation fluctuations; while adverse impacts are observed for both factors in African countries. These findings suggest the importance of precipitation for countries with vulnerable ecosystems and inform the possibility of incorporating precipitation in economic development projections under future climate trajectories.

How to cite: Leirvik, T., Yuan, M., and Karabiyik, H.: The Relative Role of Temperature and Precipitation in Global Economic Growth, EGU General Assembly 2022, Vienna, Austria, 23–27 May 2022, EGU22-11078, https://doi.org/10.5194/egusphere-egu22-11078, 2022.

15:46–15:52
|
EGU22-2470
|
ECS
|
Virtual presentation
|
Fulvia Marotta

Using an original panel data set for 24 OECD countries over the sample 1990-2019 and a standard empirical macroeconomic framework for business cycle analysis, the paper tests the combined macroeconomic effects of climate change, environmental related policies and technology. Overall, we find evidence of significant macroeconomic effects over the business cycle: physical risks act as negative demand shocks while transition risks as downward supply movements. The disruptive effects on the economy are exacerbated for countries that did not adopt a carbon tax or with a high exposure to natural disasters. In general, we find evidence that green technological development that is not supported by the right policy mix may result in market failures that have different sizes for different countries with heterogeneous consequences on the phases and duration of their respective  cycles. A  coordinated  approach  on  climate  policies  would  therefore  be  essential for instance in a monetary union with common monetary and financial objectives.

How to cite: Marotta, F.: Demand or Supply? An empirical exploration of theeffects of climate change on the macroeconomy, EGU General Assembly 2022, Vienna, Austria, 23–27 May 2022, EGU22-2470, https://doi.org/10.5194/egusphere-egu22-2470, 2022.

15:52–15:58
|
EGU22-8342
|
Highlight
|
Presentation form not yet defined
Kamil Kluza and the Climate X

Climate change brings unprecedented risks to the future stability of global financial systems and our society. Central Banks and Governments around the world have joined forces to shape new policy in response to risks driven by climate change. These regulations will require firms to proactively identify, model, quantify and manage climate-related risks for the first time.

Climate X have just completed their first of a kind Integrated Assessment Model evaluating asset-level impacts of climate-related hazards across all 22 million addressed buildings in the UK. Each building has a modelled probability, severity and a simple A-F climate rating as well as a projected loss under given scenario.  

Our geospatial core comprises of UK-specific physical risk models including flooding (pluvial, coastal, fluvial) and geohazards (subsidence and landslides). The models are at 90mx90m resolution feed UKCP18 climate scenarios of RCP8.5 and RCP2.6. Flood models are physics-based and reach a Critical Success Index (CSI) of 75%+. Geohazard models use a combination of DinSAR and machine learning modelling with 90%+ accuracy levels (measured by AUC).

Loss models combine the geospatial hazards with buildings’ exposure (square meterage) and respective vulnerabilities: age, use, material built etc. They then apply insurance-based damage curves to compute structure & content losses against building replacement costs.

 

How to cite: Kluza, K. and the Climate X: Climate X: Projecting losses due to extreme weather events linked to climate change, EGU General Assembly 2022, Vienna, Austria, 23–27 May 2022, EGU22-8342, https://doi.org/10.5194/egusphere-egu22-8342, 2022.

15:58–16:04
|
EGU22-12655
|
ECS
|
Virtual presentation
Lisa Murken, Kati Krähnert, and Christoph Gornott

This study examines the effects of (extreme) weather conditions on the willingness to purchase and on actual purchase of land ownership rights in Uganda. We use three waves of the Uganda National Panel Survey in combination with high-resolution gridded precipitation and temperature data, with which we calculate a drought index as weather shock measure, the Standardized Precipitation Evapotranspiration Index (SPEI). Using a household fixed-effects approach, we exploit spatial and temporal variation in SPEI values to causally identify the effect of extreme weather events on the willingness to acquire ownership to land and actual changes in the land ownership structure of households over time. Results show that dry conditions dampen households’ intentions to purchase land ownership rights, while wet conditions positively affect such intentions. In addition, wet conditions substantially increase the price households are willing to pay to purchase land ownership. The effects are robust to different specifications, persistent over time and translate into actual changes of land ownership ratios with a two-year time lag. The findings suggest that more favourable climatic conditions for agriculture increase interest in land ownership, which has implications for land formalisation programmes and climate change adaptation efforts.

How to cite: Murken, L., Krähnert, K., and Gornott, C.: Extreme weather effects on land ownership in Uganda, EGU General Assembly 2022, Vienna, Austria, 23–27 May 2022, EGU22-12655, https://doi.org/10.5194/egusphere-egu22-12655, 2022.

16:04–16:10
|
EGU22-4016
|
ECS
|
On-site presentation
SayedMorteza Malaekeh, Layla Shiva, and Ammar Safaie

The relative lack of research concerning the potential impacts of climate change on different sectors in developing countries, especially the Middle Eastern countries, as the essential prerequisite of climate policy actions has made these countries the frontline against climate impacts. To fill this gap, we use a non-market valuation model to assess the future impacts of climate change on agriculture in Iran. In this study, the relationship between farmland net revenue, as a proxy for land values, and climate change is investigated using a long-spanning Ricardian framework. For farm variables, we take into account novel hydro-climatic variables and climate extreme indices by taking advantage of a high-resolution meteorological dataset to tackle the sparse distribution of weather stations in Iran. For non-farm variables, we consider the pressure of rapid urbanization and migrations from rural areas in addition to socio-economic variables. This study also contributes to the body of literature through methodological improvement by taking advantage of spatial panel econometrics to develop a more robust and consistent model against spatial dependency, spatial heterogeneity, and omitted factors extraneous to the agriculture sector. The estimated coefficients are then employed in projecting long-run welfare impacts on the agricultural sector under several climate change scenarios based on the sixth phase of the Coupled Model Intercomparison Project (CMIP6) in 2050 and 2080. The results show that although climate change probably could have deleterious impacts on agriculture when we see the whole picture, its impacts would highly depend on climate zones and geographical locations. Generally, counties in snow and warm-temperate climate classes would be less susceptible to climate impacts than arid and semi-arid counties. Besides, climate change could even be beneficial for agriculture in a few counties owing to a decrease in cold extreme events frequency and intensity and an increase in growing season lengths and effective growing season degree-days. Thus, we suggest that these positive factors of climate change should be included in empirical studies to avoid overestimating the disruptive impacts of climate change. Finally, we argue that overlooking spatial dependency and spatial heterogeneity in Ricardian models could substantially affect impact assessments.

How to cite: Malaekeh, S., Shiva, L., and Safaie, A.: Climate change impacts on agriculture: do spatial spillovers matter?, EGU General Assembly 2022, Vienna, Austria, 23–27 May 2022, EGU22-4016, https://doi.org/10.5194/egusphere-egu22-4016, 2022.

16:10–16:16
|
EGU22-9157
|
ECS
|
On-site presentation
Mansi Nagpal, Jasmin Heilemann, Christian Klassert, Michael Peichl, Bernd Klauer, and Erik Gawel

Given widespread and serious implications of increasingly intense and frequent extreme events such as droughts and heat waves, there is a growing demand for integrated approaches capable of supporting prospective risk reduction through better adaption to a changing climate. While anticipating future impacts is essential to inform policy decisions, there is simultaneous need for projections at higher spatial resolution to forecast the local effects of global change. Here, we present a spatial multi-agent system (MAS) model, DroughtMAS, calibrated using a positive mathematical programming (PMP) approach. The model simulates land-use adaptation to future drought conditions, estimates the economic damages of future droughts, and assesses policy measures aimed at enhancing the drought resilience of German agriculture. It represents the biophysical and agro-economic heterogeneity of German agriculture through 23,396 individually parameterized land-user agents located on a country-wide 4x4km grid. Cropping behavior is calibrated with land-use data from high-resolution remote sensing analyses and public records and validated with independent land-use data. The economic parameters ground the model to a policy-relevant context while the statistical yield functions capture the impacts of biophysical factors on crop production. These yield functions enable the model to respond to soil moisture changes from observed data or projections from hydrological models. DroughtMAS extends the classical PMP model to capture short-run responses to droughts more realistically and analyze how fast the farmers move towards the desirable equilibrium conditions under recurring droughts. The model shows that farmers gradually adapt to prolonged drought conditions, with a lower degree of adaptation in the first drought years only slightly mitigating drought impacts. We present first analysis of future drought scenarios to demonstrate the ability of the model to quantify risks from potential droughts across Germany in monetary terms. The results provide bottom-up estimates of economic damages of droughts accounting for much needed short-run behavioral dynamics of adaptation. This provides valuable and realistic projections of future drought impacts of farm-specific changes aggregated at national scale. The model also presents spatiotemporal pattern of these impacts, showing the potential for such projections to inform targeted policy interventions. DroughtMAS provides a platform that can be extended to capture additional adaptation behaviors (e.g. drought-resilient crops, adapted crop calendars, irrigation systems) and combined with other models that require empirically validated inputs about various agricultural decision-making conditions.

How to cite: Nagpal, M., Heilemann, J., Klassert, C., Peichl, M., Klauer, B., and Gawel, E.: Simulating economic impacts of droughts on German agriculture using the country-scale Multi-Agent System model DroughtMAS, EGU General Assembly 2022, Vienna, Austria, 23–27 May 2022, EGU22-9157, https://doi.org/10.5194/egusphere-egu22-9157, 2022.

16:16–16:22
|
EGU22-12652
|
ECS
|
Presentation form not yet defined
Olexiy Kyrychenko

There is growing macro-level evidence about the negative and non-linear impact of temperature on aggregate economic output, with the temperature effects varying widely across geographical regions and extending to both agricultural and non-agricultural sectors (Hsiang, 2010; Dell et al., 2012; Burke et al.,  2015). Less is known about the country-specific micro-level mechanisms behind the temperature-output relationship and their role in adaptation to the warming climate. Addressing this knowledge gap is of considerable importance for designing effective climate change policies, especially in developing countries, which are generally exposed to higher temperatures and have limited capacity to adapt to a changing climate (Somanathan et al., 2021). This paper contributes to the progress on this issue by estimating the impact of temperature on the output of manufacturing plants in India and decomposing it into the effects on TFP and factor inputs.

The paper combines a plant-level panel of detailed production data from the formal manufacturing sector in India over 1998-2007 with high-resolution satellite-based meteorological and pollution datasets, merged at the district level. I use two approaches to construct temperature variable: a standard in the literature binned-variable and seasonal-variable approaches, both used in empirical specifications in contemporaneous and lagged forms. To isolate the role of temperature more clearly, I account for simultaneous variations in temperature and a rich set of weather and pollution controls. I further minimize the estimation biases by including plant-specific and year-by-two-digit-industry fixed effects. Standard errors are clustered at plant and district-year levels to address spatial and serial correlation.

My main findings are two-fold. First, the relationship between temperature and manufacturing output is non-linear. The output losses are especially large during the hottest season and at extreme temperatures, with more substantial losses occurring at low rather than high temperatures. This finding is consistent with the theoretical prediction from Nath (2021). An additional day with a temperature above 33°C decreases output by 0.12% or $3,749 relative to a day in the optimal interval. The comparable estimate for an additional day with a temperature below 8°C is a decrease of 0.27% and $8,435, respectively. Second, the estimated temperature-output relationship is driven by the joint effects of temperature on TFP and capital, contributing roughly 30% and 70%. The response of TFP to temperature closely follows the response of output, while the response of capital mirrors the response of output only to higher temperatures. I further decompose these primary channels to show that temperature affects TFP through its impact on labor productivity, and machinery is the most suitable for adaptation category of capital. I also find suggestive evidence of labor reallocation between seasonal manufacturing industries and between economic sectors.

These findings have important implication for adaptation. Manufacturing sector in India can adapt to changing climate by reducing the sensitivity of labor productivity to temperature and by investing in capital, prioritizing investments in machinery. Labor-related adjustments can contribute to adaptation by offsetting direct productivity losses or facilitating labor reallocation. Patterns of the seasonal responses and timing of the adjustments’ effects should also be taken into account.

How to cite: Kyrychenko, O.: Decomposition of the temperature-driven output losses in India: Plant-level evidence for the climate change adaptation policy, EGU General Assembly 2022, Vienna, Austria, 23–27 May 2022, EGU22-12652, https://doi.org/10.5194/egusphere-egu22-12652, 2022.

Justice and Inequality
16:22–16:28
|
EGU22-13236
|
ECS
|
Highlight
|
On-site presentation
|
Emma Hadré, Jonas Küpper, Janina Tschirschwitz, Melissa Mengert, and Inga Labuhn

Global warming caused by anthropogenic emissions of greenhouse gases (GHG) triggers a variety of related mechanisms including rising sea levels, heatwaves, and changes in weather regimes. The effects of global warming are not spatially homogenous; Low-income countries of the global south are more severely affected than the industrialized nations of the global north. In addition, large discrepancies between birth cohorts can be observed regarding their GHG emissions as well as exposure to the effects of climate change. Globally, calls for climate justice are emerging, and courts see an increase in so-called climate cases.

In a novel approach, we directly relate per-capita GHG emissions to the global temperature increase experienced by individual birth cohorts over their lifetime, in different world regions, and for different scenarios (Shared Socioeconomic Pathways; SSPs). Bridging the gap between emissions scenarios, temperature projections, and climate change impact, we quantify the geographical and generational inequality of climate change. This provides much-needed quantitative evidence to support the increasing number of climate cases and highlights the benefits, of staying within a low-emission scenario (1.5°C warming).

Our results suggest a grouping of world regions into high-, and low-emission regions, revealing clear geographic patterns between the global north and south when projected onto a world map. The geographic inequality regarding per-capita emissions intensifies under SSP3 and SSP5, whereas generational inequality is largest under SSP1.

We calculate an index of the ratio of GHG emissions to experienced global warming, to quantify inequality on a standardized scale, revealing the same geographic patterns and grouping of world regions observed above. Unexpectedly, the observed geographical inequality of the index is largest under SSP1 among the most recent birth cohorts, an observation that additionally pushes the debate about global justice of climate change and mitigation.

How to cite: Hadré, E., Küpper, J., Tschirschwitz, J., Mengert, M., and Labuhn, I.: Quantifying generational and geographical inequality of climate change, EGU General Assembly 2022, Vienna, Austria, 23–27 May 2022, EGU22-13236, https://doi.org/10.5194/egusphere-egu22-13236, 2022.

16:28–16:34
|
EGU22-12280
|
ECS
|
Highlight
|
On-site presentation
|
Damla Akoluk, Jazmin Zatarain Salazar, and Alexander Verbraeck

Justice in the climate context has gained more attention in the last decade. One of the main reasons is the increasingly pervasive and aggressive impact of climate change on societies and economies. Existing inequalities and disparities between sectors, regions, and generations are often exacerbated by proposed or applied policies. Hence, protecting different groups’ rights becomes more and more necessary in the climate change adaptation and mitigation policies. It is therefore essential to understand the subjective notions of the ethical principles that underlie the policies, by categorically examining these principles before taking action.

For this reason, this study explored different distributive justice principles in integrated assessment models using a descriptive approach. It resulted in a classification of the five most common ethical principles: Utilitarianism, Rawlsianism, Egalitarianism, Prioritarianism, and Sufficientarianism. These principles have been operationalized to find the optimal climate policy for future emissions. The principles have been applied to the Regional Integrated Climate-Economy (RICE) model for a comparative analysis on interregional justice.

How to cite: Akoluk, D., Zatarain Salazar, J., and Verbraeck, A.: Distributive justice principles for integrated assessment models: a comparative study on interregional justice, EGU General Assembly 2022, Vienna, Austria, 23–27 May 2022, EGU22-12280, https://doi.org/10.5194/egusphere-egu22-12280, 2022.

16:34–16:40
|
EGU22-12961
|
ECS
|
Virtual presentation
Kathryn G. Logan, Ladd Keith, Neha Gupta, Amanda J. Leinberger, Rebecca Shelton, and Katharine L. Jacobs

Decarbonisation of energy technologies is essential to meet climate change targets, however, this process has the potential to generate new or further emphasize pre-existing inequalities within society. By ensuring a low carbon energy transition is sustainable and equitable, trade-offs and co-benefits between decarbonisation and other U.S. policy objectives can be achieved. This is important as many communities are in the process of developing or updating their climate action plans (CAPs). The ‘success’ of a CAP is often measured against the greenhouse gas emission forecast for a baseline year and does not consider the wider implications in terms of environmental impacts or impacts to the individuals it directly affects.

We present a theoretical framework to aid decision makers to ensure energy justice is incorporated when designing CAPs. This framework expands on several key principles incorporated into the tenets of energy justice. These principles include energy availability, reliability and affordability, high-quality employment, access to information, objective governance, intersectional responsibility, intra-generational equity, intergenerational equity, and due process. This framework aims to reduce the disproportional burdens of transitioning towards a low carbon energy future by understanding why these key principles should be integrated into new and amended CAPs.

How to cite: Logan, K. G., Keith, L., Gupta, N., Leinberger, A. J., Shelton, R., and Jacobs, K. L.: Integrating energy justice with community climate action planning, EGU General Assembly 2022, Vienna, Austria, 23–27 May 2022, EGU22-12961, https://doi.org/10.5194/egusphere-egu22-12961, 2022.